Comenius Project: Green Skills for Global Change, Santa Clara school partner´ blog
European Union funded Comenius Project
ANTROPOLOGIA INDIANA UNIVERSITY
miércoles, 31 de diciembre de 2014
sábado, 27 de diciembre de 2014
domingo, 21 de diciembre de 2014
CRONICAS DEL VALLE BAJO DESDE LO LOCAL A LO PROVINCIAL, NACIONAL Y MUNDIAL: CRONICA DE UNA NEVADA EN EL AÑO 1987 Al comen...
CRONICAS DEL VALLE BAJO DESDE LO LOCAL A LO PROVINCIAL, NACIONAL Y MUNDIAL: CRONICA DE UNA NEVADA EN EL AÑO 1987
Al comen...: CRONICA DE UNA NEVADA EN EL AÑO 1987 Al comenzar a escribir estas líneas en el blog personalizado, en principio quiero dar ...
Al comen...: CRONICA DE UNA NEVADA EN EL AÑO 1987 Al comenzar a escribir estas líneas en el blog personalizado, en principio quiero dar ...
domingo, 14 de diciembre de 2014
miércoles, 10 de diciembre de 2014
domingo, 7 de diciembre de 2014
viernes, 5 de diciembre de 2014
Discovering why wild salmon is in decline - Information Centre - Research
Discovering why wild salmon is in decline - Information Centre - Research: Discovering why wild salmon is in decline - Information Centre - Research
lunes, 24 de noviembre de 2014
Passenger Pigeon Extinct 100 Years Ago Today
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
sábado, 1 de noviembre de 2014
AZTI-Tecnalia | Marine Biotechnology
AZTI-Tecnalia | Marine Biotechnology
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
martes, 28 de octubre de 2014
jueves, 16 de octubre de 2014
TLC = Tratado de Libre Colonización
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
domingo, 5 de octubre de 2014
miércoles, 24 de septiembre de 2014
domingo, 21 de septiembre de 2014
Andrew Newsham on Adapting to Climate Change
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
sábado, 6 de septiembre de 2014
Jeffrey Sachs: The Path to Sustainable Development
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
lunes, 28 de julio de 2014
A Life Going Begging A presentation of some Spanish traditions
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
viernes, 25 de julio de 2014
J. R. Lengomin: MAQUETAS (Barcos)
J. R. Lengomin: MAQUETAS (Barcos): Estas maquetas no parten de la base de las que se venden para armar, estas son totalmente artesanales y unicas. Cada pieza se fabrica manua...
miércoles, 16 de julio de 2014
domingo, 6 de julio de 2014
sábado, 28 de junio de 2014
miércoles, 11 de junio de 2014
Inés Celis Cossío: el viaje a Eslovenia, en el segundo meeting del Proyecto Comenius Green Skills for Global Change
By Inés Celis Cossío, 1ºH bachillerato Instituto Santa Clara. Santander, Cantabria. Spain
English Relato de Mi Viaje a Eslovenia 2014
lunes, 9 de junio de 2014
domingo, 8 de junio de 2014
Alan Jones - James Delingpole | 2GB Alan talks to the English columnist and novelist about wind power and alternative energy fraud
AUDIO Alan talks to the English columnist and novelist about wind power and alternative energy fraud
Alan Jones - James Delingpole | 2GB
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
Alan Jones - James Delingpole | 2GB
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
sábado, 31 de mayo de 2014
viernes, 23 de mayo de 2014
GMOFormulaBaby-forweb
GMOFormulaBaby-forweb
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
martes, 13 de mayo de 2014
martes, 29 de abril de 2014
General Electric To Invest $1 Billion A Year In Renewable Projects | ThinkProgress
General Electric To Invest $1 Billion A Year In Renewable Projects | ThinkProgress
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
jueves, 17 de abril de 2014
sábado, 12 de abril de 2014
jueves, 10 de abril de 2014
Fracking Hell: The Untold Story
Fracking Hell: The Untold Story
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
domingo, 6 de abril de 2014
Resilience Dictionary
Resilience dictionary
source http://www.stockholmresilience.org/4.aeea46911a3127427980004355.html
Here you find a list of quick definitions to the many different terms that are used within resilience research.
Resilience is the capacity to deal with change and continue to develop.
Social-ecological systems are linked systems of people and nature. The term emphasizes that humans must be seen as a part of, not apart from, nature — that the delineation between social and ecological systems is artificial and arbitrary. Scholars have also used concepts like ‘coupled human-environment systems´, ‘ecosocial systems´ and ‘socioecological systems´ to illustrate the interplay between social and ecological systems. The term social-ecological system was coined by Fikret Berkes and Carl Folke in 1998 because they did not want to treat the social or ecological dimension as a prefix, but rather give the two same weight during their analysis.
Ecosystem resilience is a measure of how much disturbance (like storms, fire or pollutants) an ecosystem can handle without shifting into a qualitatively different state. It is the capacity of a system to both withstand shocks and surprises and to rebuild itself if damaged.
Social resilience is the ability of human communities to withstand and recover from stresses, such as environmental change or social, economic or political upheaval. Resilience in societies and their life-supporting ecosystems is crucial in maintaining options for future human development.
Ecosystem Services are the benefits people obtain from ecosystem processes. These include water and air purification, flood control, erosion control, generation of fertile soils, detoxification of wastes, resistance to climate and other environmental changes, pollination, and aesthetic and cultural benefits that derive from nature.
Vulnerability refers to the propensity of social and ecological system to suffer harm from exposure to external stresses and shocks. Research on vulnerability can, for example, assess how large the risk is that people and ecosystems will be affected by climate changes and how sensitive they will be to such changes. Vulnerability is often denoted the antonym of resilience.
Institutions are the norms and rules that shape human interactions. They can be formal (such as rules and laws) or informal (such as norms, conventions and self-imposed codes of conduct). Institutions, such as property rights, can be used to link society to nature with the aim to control people´s use of the environment for both ecological and human long-term objectives.
Complex Adaptive Systems (CAS) include companies, the weather, our immune systems, the economy, ecosystems, single cells and brains. In these CAS simple rules of cause and effect do not apply, they are complex, unpredictable and constantly adapting to their environments. Hence, they are far from being machines that you can take apart and investigate the parts to understand the whole.
Response diversity refers to the multitude of responses to environmental change and disturbances, among species contributing to the same ecosystem function. This kind of diversity plays a crucial role in sustaining the resilience of ecosystems to cope with disturbance and change. If all species within a functional group (e.g. pollinators, seed dispersers or decomposers) are equally sensitive to a particular disturbance the system will have low response diversity and be vulnerable to that particular disturbance.
Anthropocene is a term coined in 2000 by the Nobel Prize winning scientist Paul Crutzen. It describes the most recent period in the Earth's history, starting in the 18th century, when the activities of humans first began to have a significant global impact on the Earth's climate and ecosystems.
Natural Capital is an extension of the traditional economic notion of capital. The term was coined to represent the natural assets that economists, governments, and corporations tend to leave off the balance sheets. Natural capital can be non-renewable resources, like fossil fuels and mineral deposits; renewable resources, such as fish or timber; or ecosystem services (for instance the generation of fertile soils, pollination, or purification of air and water).
Social Capital is a concept used in various fields, from economics and political science to sociology and natural resources management. Broadly, it refers to social relations and among individuals and the norms and social trust which they generate and which facilitate coordination and cooperation for mutual benefit.
.
Adaptive co-management is an approach based on collaboration among multiple actors, for instance agencies, researchers and local resource users. Management of everything from local fisheries to global climate change is regarded as controlled experiments, with the consequent need for monitoring, evaluation and constant improvement. According to a growing number of scholars such management that is flexible and open to learning stimulates a sustainable development by enhancing resilience in coupled human and natural systems.
Blue and green water: ‘Blue water´ is the liquid water in rivers, lakes and ground water. ‘‘Green water´ is the water that feeds the system as rain and forms soil moisture that is absorbed by plants (and then exhaled as vapour flow). When discussing the water needed to produce food for an expanding human population we tend to neglect the green water flows even though most food production comes from rain-fed farming, not least in hunger and poverty stricken areas with rapid population growth.
Urban sprawl is a phenomenon that plagues cities in both developing and industrial countries. It is an uncontrolled or unplanned extension of urban areas into the countryside that tends to result in an inefficient and wasteful use of land and its associated natural resources.
lunes, 31 de marzo de 2014
ERRORES EN LA UE CON WIND AND SOLAR ENERGY INVESTMENT soaring energy bills: a failure of the EU ?
http://www.sepp.org/key_issues/soaring_energy_bills.pdf
AN OPEN LETTER TO THE MEMBERS OF THE EU’S PARLIAMENT
SOARING ENERGY BILLS: A FAILURE OF THE EU?
By
Franco Battaglia1
Professor of Chemical Physics and Environmental Chemistry
Università di Modena, Italy
0. Introduction
The EU’s energy policy of the last 20 years has been dead wrong, to say the least. Here it is in a nutshell:
1) It is based on the assumption that human activities have a bad influence on climate, mainly due to
CO2 emissions.
2) In order to reduce CO2 emissions several actions are needed: promote renewables, mainly sun and
wind energy; promote energy saving; promote energy efficiency.
3) All the above will have the beneficial side effect of creating jobs, thereby increasing wellness and
providing prosperity; in a word, this is the green economy.
The purpose of this paper is to show you that the three items above are – all of them – wrong. In particular,
I’ll show that:
1) Human activities have had no detectable impact on climate.
2) Most importantly – aside from the fact that even if they had an impact on climate (and they do not) it
might even be beneficial – whatever the consequences on climate, reducing CO2 emissions will
jeopardize our well being, our civilization, and even our own life. Enacting the EU policy could
mean the death of millions and sentence billions of people in the developing world to lives of
continued poverty and short lifespans: Securing energy, not climate, is the real problem mankind
has to face.
3) Solar energy (specifically, wind and photovoltaic technologies) is a fraud and no CO2-emission
reduction can be expected from them. Energy saving is the most dangerous maneuver we could
make, and energy efficiency, as good to pursue as it might be, does not help in tackling our real
problem.
4) Not by producing energy but by consuming energy jobs are created: the green economy is a scam.
1. Nature, not human activity, rules the climate
I am a member of the NIPCC (Non-governmental International Panel on Climate Change). NIPCC has
evaluated the same scientific literature at disposal of the more famous IPCC, which, together with Al Gore,
received a Nobel Price in 2007. It was a Nobel Price for Peace, not for Science. And, indeed, the members of
the NIPCC, most of which are experienced and distinguished scientists, conclude that IPCC’s resolutions are
scientifically very questionable. This paper does not focus on climate, so I will only briefly touch on the
matter.
During the last century global temperatures are believed to have been higher than about four centuries ago.
How many times have you heard statements like: «Temperatures of the last 20 years have been higher than
ever recorded in the last 400 hundred years». Generally, statements such as the above are true, but what do
they mean, and are they alarming? The line of reasoning goes on as follows. «During the last century,
industrialization, together with emissions of the greenhouse gas CO2, took place at the same time with global
warming. Therefore, human activities are responsible for global warming». It is a lovely, worthwhile to be
explored in depth, conjecture, which I shall call the climate/human connection conjecture or, for short, the
climate conjecture. As lovely as it might be, however, the climate conjecture is not supported by scientific
evidence, as I’ll show.
1
I
acknowledge
Dr.
Roger
Cohen
for
valuable
discussions
on
the
matters
of
this
paper.
Let me start by noticing that there is something quite remarkable about it. Throughout scientific history, the
most revolutionary conjectures have been proposed. Sometimes, they appeared to be quite absurd or, at any
rate, against common sense. However, what is extraordinary about science is that any conjecture, no matter
how extravagant, if it has elements of truth, the more it is investigated the more its soundness emerges.
Conversely, if a conjecture is wrong, the more it is investigated the more emerges as being wrong. A popular
paradigm of absurdity is Einstein’s relativity theory. The whole theory stands on the following absurd
postulate: the speed of light in vacuum is one and the same independently of the speed of the light source.
This not only sounds absurd, but is also incomprehensible. For, you know that if, inside a train riding at 100
km/h, your friend fires a bullet towards the locomotive, she measures the bullet’s speed to be, say, 200 km/h,
but you, who are standing at the station platform and measure the train’s and friend’s speed to be 100 km/h,
you measure the bullet’s speed to be 300 km/h. However, if your friend fires a photon, then you and your
friend measure for the photon the same speed. Nonsense. Yet, it doesn’t take long to confirm that this
“nonsense” is what reality is. And it didn’t take long to verify several other “nonsense” of the theory of
relativity.
Now, back to climate. Billions of dollars have been devoted to the climate conjecture stated above. And, as
said, it was a quite reasonable conjecture (i.e., not as extravagant as the invariance of the speed of light). Yet,
nothing has emerged to support that conjecture. Let me just mention a few points.
1. The human CO2 emissions of the last century have been exceptional in history. But has the climate
of the last century also been exceptional? The answer is no. The most recent warming period – as
warm as the present one – was what geologists call the Medieval Warm Period, proved to be so
worldwide (see Fig. 1, taken from the First IPCC Report). You might question the reliability of data
concerning a time so far in the past, but if you do so, i.e., if you say that data so far in the past are not
reliable, then you do not have right to insist that the climate today is warmer than in the past. Either
you say that the methods that allow geologists to reconstruct the past climate are reliable, which
means that you are allowed to assert that the climate today is warmer than 400 years ago and as
warm as the climate of 1000 years ago. Or, you say that geologists might be wrong about the past,
which means that you cannot compare today’s climate with climate of the past. In the first case –
which is what I am inclined to agree with – you should explain what has made medieval climate as
warm as today’s. And this has not been explained by IPCC. There is a paper which purported to
show that the Medieval Warm Period did not exist, but we now know that the paper was tainted by
biased data selection and analysis.
Fig. 1 – Global temperature of the last 1000 years
2. As you can see from Fig. 1, the present warm period did not start 100 years or so ago, i.e., didn’t
start following the Industrial Revolution’s CO2 emissions. And a necessary (though not sufficient)
condition for action A to be the cause of action B is that B must follow A. The present warm period
started about 400 years ago, well before the Industrial Revolution, at the minimum of what
geologists call the Little Ice Age. The question then arises: why did the climate start getting warmer
400 years ago? Whatever the answer, it cannot be because of the Industrial Revolution.
3. Of course, in striving hold on to the climate conjecture, you could still maintain that without human
emissions the climate wouldn’t have been so warm. However, it just happened that with human
emissions the climate got actually colder. As you can see in Fig. 2, in the years 1945-1970 – during
and right after the baby-boom, industrial-boom and emission-boom period – the climate did get
colder. Cold to the point that during the Seventies there was, as popular as the global-warming fear
is today, a fear for an oncoming glacial era (or, at any rate, for an oncoming period of global
cooling). So, you do have a proof that the climate conjecture is quite wrong: things have happened
that are the opposite than those expected from the conjecture. Somebody has claimed that the
cooling was due to the concomitant emission of cooling-inducing sulfate molecules, and that when
sulfate-reducing policies have been enforced the cooling has disappeared. This cannot be so:
protocols to reduce sulfate emissions were signed in 1980 and became operative no earlier than
1990, i.e., respectively, 10 and 20 years later than when the climate again began to warm up. Once
again, you have an effect occurring before the alleged cause. However, without entering this
possibly endless debate, lets move on.
Fig. 2 – Global temperature of the last 120 years
4. There is no doubt that worldwide emissions have never been reduced since they started, not even
during the last 10 years. Actually, they have kept increasing, as usual. Yet no warming has been
recorded during the last 10 years or so (see Fig. 3), and this contradicts, once again, the climate
conjecture.
Fig. 3 – Global temperature of the last 10 years
5. In the 90’s emerged is been called the human-induced-global-warming fingerprint: The theory based
on the climate conjecture predicts that the troposphere, at about 10 km above the ground at and near
the Equator, should warm up more than it does at ground level.
Fig. 4 – Troposphere temperature pattern according to the human-induced
global warming conjecture
More precisely, the troposphere’s temperature pattern should be, according to the theory, the one
displayed in Fig. 4. In it, along the x-axis there is the North Pole to the left, the Equator in the middle
and the South Pole to the right; the altitude increases along the y-axis. The theory grounded on the
climate conjecture predicts, at about 10 km up in the equatorial troposphere, a warming which
should be at least twice the warming at the ground level. What the observations have to say on this is
shown in Fig. 5, where satellite records prove that at 10 km up in the equatorial troposphere no
increased warming, even less doubled, is observed. Actually, a cooling is observed.
Fig. 5 – Troposphere temperature pattern according to satellite measurements
6. In conclusion, striving to control the climate is a futile engagement because the climate/human
connection conjecture is false. On top of that, several analyses conclude that the warming the
planet has experienced during the last 400 years has had beneficial consequences. However, bad or
good as the consequences of a warmer world might be, striving to reduce CO2 emissions is a futile
engagement, because reducing CO2 emissions is an impossible task.
2. Reducing CO2 emissions is virtually impossible
The Kyoto Protocol aimed at reducing CO2 emissions by 6% below the 1990’s level by the year 2012. Has
this goal been achieved? Not even barely: the emissions are today higher than those of 1990, as Fig. 6 shows,
where you can read the world’s primary energy consumption from fossil fuels (in million tons equivalent of
oil) in 1990 and 2010.
WORLD’S PRIMARY ENERGY CONSUMPTION
FROM FOSSIL FUELS (CO2)
Year
1990
2010
Mteo
7400
9800
Fig. 6 – World’s energy consumption from fossil fuels
According to the 20-20-20 energy package, the EU has agreed to reduce CO2 emissions down to at least
20% below the 1990 level by the year 2020. Is this goal going to be achieved? Just the opposite: the
emissions today are actually higher than those of 1990. Fig. 7 shows the numbers.
Fig. 7 – EU’s energy consumption from fossil fuels
You might think that the EU is on the right track to achieve the goal: after all, some reduction has indeed
occurred during the last few years (mainly due to the economic crisis). Fig. 8 clarifies the point: nothing
worth mentioning has really occurred.
Fig. 8 – EU’s energy consumption since 1990
EU’S PRIMARY ENERGY CONSUMPTION
FROM FOSSIL FUELS (CO2)
Year
1990
2010
Mteo
1380
1400
The 20-20-20 EU energy package also says that the renewables contribution to the primary-energy
consumption should be 20% by the year 2020. How the EU is doing on this is shown in Fig. 9, where you
can see that the renewables contribution to the EU’s energy consumption, which was 5% in 1990, is now less
than 9%, quite far from the 20% goal.
EU’S PRIMARY ENERGY CONSUMPTION [2010]
Fossil Fuels
79%
Nuclear
12% (100 GW)
Hydro+Biomass+Waste+Geo
6.5%
Wind+Solar
2.2%+0.3%
Fig. 9 – EU’s primary-energy-consumption share by fuels
Is the EU doing, at least, any better than the rest of the world? Fig. 10 shows that the renewables contribution
to the world’s energy consumption, which was 8% in 1990, is now 9%, as much as that of the EU, after all.
WORLD’S PRIMARY ENERGY CONSUMPTION [2010]
Fossil Fuels
85%
Nuclear
6% (300 GW)
Hydro+Biomass+Waste+Geo
8%
Wind+Solar
1%
Fig. 10 – World’s primary-energy-consumption share by fuels
The last “20” of the 20-20-20 EU’s energy package refers to energy efficiency, which we shall comment on
later. For the time being the pressing question that arises is: Why, in spite of all the commitment that the EU
and the entire world have taken during the last 20 years, almost nothing has been achieved? After all, the one
in Durban last year has been the COP17, the 17th Conference of the Parties: earnest and influential people
gathered together 17 times in 17 years, but have really achieved next to nothing. Politicians have argued for
17 years without reaching any agreement on how to find €100 billion to tackle a problem that does not exist.
Please keep in mind that: the fact that this year’s COP in Qatar is COP18 means that there have been already
17 failures. So, the question is: Why has there been so much effort with so much failure?
The answer to the question is quite simple: no CO2 reduction is possible, not the Kyoto’s 6%, even less the
EU’s 20%. The proof itself is astonishingly simple. Look again at Fig. 10, to understand why the Kyoto
Protocol was an impossible dream. 85% of our energy consumption comes from fossil fuels, i.e., 85% of
what we do is done by emitting CO2: we emit CO2 even at night while sleeping, because our refrigerators,
our heating systems during the winter, our cooling systems during the summer, are at work. Almost all of
whatever we do, we do by emitting CO2. From Fig. 10 you also see that all the nuclear power in the world
avoids about 6% of the emissions, i.e., if there were no nuclear plants, our emissions would have been about
6% higher. As Fig. 10 specifies, their total output is 300 GW. To achieve another 6% we could then build
about 300 large nuclear reactors, which would require about €1 trillion in capital investment. How many
nuclear reactors are under construction worldwide? About 60, one fifth of what is needed. Notice that the
economic commitment to reach this goal by means of the nuclear power is 10 times larger than the
commitment on which the rulers of the world were unable to reach any agreement in 17 years.
Likewise, the EU’s 20% emission reduction is impossible. Please, look at Fig. 9. There you see that nuclear
power avoids about 10% of the EU’s CO2 emissions, i.e., without nuclear power EU’s CO2 emissions would
be 10% higher. A further 20% reduction would require, at least, 100 new nuclear plants to be installed before
2020. However, the nuclear plants under construction in EU are just…2: what is being pursued is a CO2-
emission reduction of not even 0.2%.
As you should have been convinced by now, little CO2-emission reduction is possible from nuclear power;
which, like it or not, would be the most effective way to do so. To make things worse, consider what happens
if one tries to achieve the goal without resorting to nuclear power, that is by installing wind and photovoltaic
plants. We have already noticed that to produce 300 GW-electric necessary to satisfy the Kyoto Protocol
would require a capital investment of €1 trillion for the 300 nuclear reactors needed. To produce 300 GWelectric
from wind, wind farms of about 1500 GW capacity would be needed, with an economic burden, in
capital investment, not less than €1.5 trillion (not to mention that they would be about 1.5 millions wind
towers). Furthermore, to produce 300 GW-electric from solar photovoltaic (PV) technology, there should be
installed a PV power of about 3000 GW, with an economic burden, in capital investment, not less than €15
trillion! In case you are wondering why to produce 300 GW we need 1500 GW in wind power and 3000 GW
in PV power, the short but sufficient answer is: Because the wind doesn’t blow and the sun doesn’t shine 24
hours a day.
Now you understand why the 17 COPs have been 17 failures, why COP18 in Qatar, next November, will be
the 18-th failure, and why no CO2-emission reduction has been achieved: as long as we have fossil fuels
available, no reduction is possible. More precisely: meaningless reduction is presently possible with
nuclear power, even less with wind power or, worse, with solar power.
3. Energy, not climate, is the real problem
«As long as we have fossil fuels available», I wrote in the last sentence above. From Fig. 10 we see that 85%
of world’s energy consumption comes from fossil fuels: almost all we do can be done thanks to fossil fuels.
Fig. 11 shows the world’s oil yearly production as a function of time [R.J. Brecha et al., Am. J. Phys. 75, 916
(2007) and references therein].
Fig. 11 – Hubbert’s peak of oil
The points show the actual yearly production. The lower continuous curve is the Hubbert curve, drawn
assuming a total amount of oil of about 2 trillion barrels, which is the best estimate available. By the end of
the century oil production will be at the 1900 level. But the real problem is not the end of oil: The real
problem will occur when Hubbert’s curve will be at its maximum – Hubbert’s peak – when oil demand starts
to be greater than oil production: the geo-political consequences of the circumstance I shall leave to your
imagination. As you can see, the world is sitting on top of Hubbert’s peak. And, if the best estimate available
were wrong and the total amount of oil were about 3 trillion barrels, Hubbert’s peak will occur before 20
years from now, as the upper continuous curve shows: you should keep in mind that every billion barrel of
oil discovered shifts Hubbert’s peak by 6 days. So, either the world, sitting on Hubbert’s peak, is late with
the actions to be taken to minimize the consequences of the necessarily diminished oil production; or,
Hubbert’s peak will occur 20 years form now and, by acting now the world will avoid to the next generation
the uneasy situation we could be now in case we are, after all, sitting on top of Hubbert’s peak.
If you still wonder about how faithful these predictions are, let me tell you two things. First, the oil’s
Hubbert’s peak will occur, simply because our planet is round and finite and not flat and infinite. Second, a
peak (not Hubbert’s peak) has already occurred for sure. Fig. 12 displays the oil production per year and per
person as a function of time [A. Bartlett, Physics Today 57(7), 53 (2004)].
Fig. 12 – Yearly world oil production per person
As you can see, it is since 1980 that the world produces human beings faster than oil: please, keep that in
mind. You see, 80% of the cost of what you have on your desk at lunchtime is energy cost, and, as several
times noted, almost all energy we use comes from fossil fuels, half of which is oil. Modern agriculture could
be defined as the transformation of oil into food: no oil, no food. Succeeding in reducing, even slightly,
fossil-fuel consumption, might mean to skip breakfast, for the 1 billion people living in the developed
countries, but for the 1 billion people starving to death, it would mean to die because of starvation.
The fact is that ours is the Oil Age. Seen in the context of the centuries, Hubbert’s peak is what is shown in
Fig. 13.
Fig. 13 – The Hubbert’s peak of oil
Each civilization has been labeled with a specific symbol by the following civilizations: the Egyptian one
with the Pyramids, the Greek and Roman civilizations with the Athens’ Acropolis and Coliseum, and so on.
Hubbert’s peak is most probably the symbol how the future civilizations will label ours.
Ours is the Oil Age or, better, it is the Age of abundant and cheap energy. We should be grateful to God for
having allowed us to live in it. For, during the millennia to the left of Hubbert’s peak the energy needs of the
past civilizations were satisfied by slavery. You should keep in mind that at the time of the Egyptian, Greek
or Roman civilizations, 90% of the population was kept in slavery. Which is not a today’s taboo of a
thousand-years-ago habit: you should not forget that Gone with the wind was taking place, in America, just
150 years ago, when there were 4 million slaves within a population of 30 million citizens. Like it or not,
you should realize that slavery became a taboo not because of socialist fights, but because of the invention of
thermal and electric engines and devices.
What was that supplied the energy needs of the past civilizations from the Stone Age for all the millennia up
to the beginning of the Oil Age, i.e., to the left of Hubbert’s peak? It was solar energy, 100% solar energy,
i.e., wood and slavery. Look now again at Fig. 10, which shows that today the solar-energy contribution
(hydropower, biomass, wind and direct solar) to the world energy consumption is less than 9%. You see,
then, that solar energy is the energy of the past: 100% for millennia until a couple of centuries ago, less
than 9% today.
The question then arises of whether solar energy could be the energy of the future, the energy that will feed
the needs of the civilizations prospering (hopefully) to the right of Hubbert’s peak. The answer is no. And it
is so for technical reasons: no matter how deep goes our research and how advanced gets our technology, we
cannot ask the sun when to shine or the winds when to blow. All this shall soon be clarified. Before that, let
me comment on one point. The fuel of past civilization, for several millennia, has been the sun, 100% sun
energy. During all those millennia when the energy needs of all civilizations have been satisfied for 100% by
sun energy, the world population has been below half billion people. We are now 7 billion. For sun energy
to be the energy fuel of the civilizations prospering (hopefully) to the right of Hubbert’s peak, at least
6 billions of us has to die. You start to see, now, to where the EU’s energy policy is heading.
4. Wind and photovoltaic technologies are a fraud
Apart from fossil-fuel, nuclear, geothermal, and urban-waste energy, everything else is solar energy:
hydropower, biomass, wind and direct solar are, all, solar energy. As has already been stressed, the fuel that
satisfied the energy needs of past civilizations, since the remotest times until a couple of centuries ago, was
100% solar energy, whereas today’s solar-energy contribution is less than a tiny 9%: solar energy is the
energy of the past. Solar-energy technologies, however, do not contribute with similar share. Quite the
contrary: of those 9 points, 8 are due to hydropower (to biomass, in poor countries; i.e., wood, is the major
solar contribution in those countries, and it is so for the same reason for which wood was the leading fuel of
the past civilizations for millennia).
Actually there are countries – such as Norway or Paraguay – where hydropower provides 100% of their
electricity needs. Modern technologies – wind power and photovoltaic (PV) technology – are, everywhere,
irrelevant. Wind power and PV contributions to the world energy needs are, respectively, less than 1% and
less than 0.01% (see Fig. 10). Even in countries that have strongly committed themselves to these
technologies, the contribution from them is nothing worthwhile to mention, in comparison with the effort
taken. In Fig. 9 you can see the contribution of these technologies to the primary energy needs in the EU
countries: 2.2% from wind and 0.3% from photovoltaic technologies. However, it is electric energy that
these technologies produce, and to be fair it is with electric production (rather than with primary energy) that
comparison should be made. You may read this comparison in Fig. 14: Wind and PV contribution to the
EU’s electric needs is about 5%, of which 90% from wind and 10% from PV technologies.
Germany is the country most committed to wind and PV technologies. In 2010 its installed wind capacity
was about 27 GW (more than 25000 wind towers!), whereas its installed nuclear capacity was about 17 GW.
And 17 GW was also its installed PV capacity: in practice, half of PV modules of the world are in Germany.
However, whereas in 2010 nuclear power contributed 23% to the German electricity demand, wind
contributed 6% and PV 2%. The capital investment of those wind and PV plants has certainly been higher
than €100 billions: with that money Germany could have installed 30 GW in new nuclear plants that could
have provided not 8% but 40% of its electric needs.
EU’S ELECTRIC ENERGY CONSUMPTION [2010]
Fossil Fuels
51%
Nuclear
27% (100 GW)
Hydro
12%
Biomass+Waste+Geo
5%
Wind+Solar
4.4%+0.6%
Fig. 14 – EU’s electric-energy-consumption share by fuels
If I gave you the impression that the problem with wind and PV technologies is that they are very expensive,
I was wrong. They are very expensive indeed, but this is not their problem. It is a problem – a fantastic
problem, as a matter of fact – but it is not their real problem. To understand what their real problem is, you
have to understand how we make use of energy and, in particular, how electric energy works.
Energy is a good that you have to have available exactly when required; otherwise it is useless. This is why,
among renewables, hydropower and biomass take the lion share: energy is stored in a log of wood, ready to
be burned at will; and energy is stored behind a dam in the water, ready to make it fall on the turbines at will.
On top of that, electric energy has to be produced as demanded and has to be used as produced: a slight
unbalance will cause blackouts. For, we don’t know how to store electric energy. And there are fundamental
reasons of physics why we don’t know that. I don’t want to go into technicalities, but this is the reason why
we don’t have electric cars.
Figs. 15 – Electric power-load curves of Italy and of a few European countries
To fully understand the problem without too many technicalities, we have to consider the daily electricity
demand. It is shown in Fig. 15 for Italy and for a few other countries. On the x axis of both figures you can
read the hours of the day, on the y axis the power demanded: for Italy, it is shown the actual power, in MW;
for other countries, the power of each country has been renormalized to its average demand, so to make a
sensible comparison between the countries. The point of showing both figures is that the general pattern of
these load curves is the same for all. 1) The electricity demand never goes to zero: Italy, for instance,
demands at least 30 GW 24 hours a day, which is Italy’s base load. As you see from Fig. 15, the base load of
each country is at least 70% of its average electric-power demand. 2) There are hours of the day when the
load reaches a peak, typically around 10 AM and around 7 PM.
To produce electricity according to the load curve (and it has to be so produced, otherwise the system suffers
blackouts), each country may use, at will, any conventional technology (hydropower, coal, natural gas,
nuclear). There are countries that use 100% hydropower (Norway, for instance), and there are countries that
prefer nuclear (for instance, from nuclear power France produces 80% of its electricity consumption).
However, apart from those exceptions, in general, each country has its own mix, which depends on several
factors, mainly technical, but also political. It is the favorable orography and its limited population that
allows Norway to use hydropower for 100% of its needs. And it is thanks to the abundant availability of coal
in Germany that it is coal that provides about 50% of Germany’s electricity needs. And are obvious the
reasons why Saudi Arabia produces its electricity, fifty-fifty, form oil and natural gas.
Could wind and photovoltaic (PV) technology take any part in this share? Unfortunately no. Could they give
any contribution to the base load (which is, by the way, at least 70% of the average demand)? Certainly not
the PV technology: the base load is, by definition, the load required 24 hours a day, and the sun does not
shine for half of that time. Could they give any contribution to the peak load? Again, certainly not the PV
technology: one of the peaks occurs at around 7 PM, when it is dark. Well, PV modules may contribute when
the sun shines, you would say. It is not so. For, in very cloudy days PV plants produce no power.
Just the same it is with wind: the electric system cannot rely on wind, which blows at its will, not ours.
The bottom line is that the electric system has to have as many conventional plants as the peak load requires.
Differently said, no matter how many gigawatts you install in wind towers or PV roofs, you cannot shutdown
a single watt of conventional power. You may shutdown a 1-GW nuclear reactor and put a 1-GW coal plant
into operation; you may shutdown a 1-GW coal plant and put a 1-GW hydropower plant into operation
(orography allowing), but you cannot install wind turbines or PV roofs for 1, 10, 100 GW and shutdown a
single conventional watt.
Germany is an example for all of us. It has installed 44 GW in wind and PV power: has it, because of that,
shutdown a single coal plant? No. Or did it shutdown a single nuclear plant? Actually, just the opposite: a
few weeks before the 2011 earthquake in Japan, Mrs. Merkel’s government had approved a life extension for
several nuclear plants. Quite peculiar for a country that had spent more than €100 billions in 44 GW of
“green” power. Since the Fukushima events, Mrs. Merkel, having changed her mind, has closed one third of
Germany’s nuclear plants, but those “green” 44 GW have been of no help: the price Germany is paying for
the missing nuclear plants is that it has both increased electricity production from inland coal and imported
natural gas and decreased its electric-energy export/import balance.
You see, now, that wind and PV technologies are useless: their contribution to the load curve is virtually
zero. It’s not a matter of costs: if the wind tower and the PV modules were free, they would be as much
useless. Simply, they do not fit within the electric system. If the roofs of the European houses were all
covered, by some magic, by photovoltaic modules, we would still need all the conventional plant we have
now.
Allow me a metaphor. For your transportation needs it is pretty enough for you to have a car (unless you
need to go overseas). Would you change your car for a bicycle? No, you wouldn’t go too far. Yet, you do
have a bike. Why? Because, given that a bike costs 100 times less than a car, there are occasions when the
bike can do the job and you save money on gasoline. Would you have a bike if its cost were 10 times more
than that of a car? I doubt. Perhaps you would, even up to the point of buying a bike instead of a car, if the
bike were a reliable substitute for the car, but this is not the case. It is just the same with those “green”
plants: they are, mostly, useless, even if they were free. On top of that, far from being free, they are even 40
times more expensive than conventional plants.
You now should agree with me that the only function they provide is to save on conventional fuel. Exactly as
the bicycle has the merit of avoiding you to burn gasoline, the only merit wind and PV plants have is to make
you saving on fossil fuels when the wind blows or the sun shines. A saving that, as I shall soon show you,
has nothing to do with future-generations needs.
And here we come at the heart of our discussion: when, being to the right of Hubbert’s bell, there won’t be
any fossil fuel to save, those “green” plants, having lost their only function of saving fossil fuels, will then be
totally useless. This is why solar energy cannot power the world in the future. And you better don’t bet on
research and technology developments: no research, no technology advancement will ever make the sun
shine or the winds blow differently than how they do.
5. Energy saving, energy efficiency, and creating jobs
There is a lot of misunderstanding about energy saving and energy efficiency. For instance, we concluded
last section by proving that the only purpose of producing electricity from wind and PV plants is to save on
conventional fuel. But this is not energy saving. And, if you insist that this is energy saving, then I can show
you that energy saving is a futile engagement.
If energy saving were oil saving, why should we save on oil? Perhaps, because it is our duty to give the
future generations development opportunities similar to those have been granted to our generation. It was not
me who made up such a good reason to save on oil, but somebody much cleverer than me, who even gave a
name to the reason: sustainable development. Développement durable, to word it in French. Let’s do the
math, though, and compute what might the benefits be, on future generations, from our oil saving, which we
would do because otherwise oil will come to an end in less than 100 years. How much savings? To settle
things once and for all, let’s assume that the EU saves 100% of the oil it consumes: let’s say that starting
from tomorrow European countries store somewhere, in a safe place, the whole oil they would have
otherwise used. When, 100 years from now, the oil of the world will be gone and the European countries will
open their oil repositories, given that EU’s countries use less than 20% of world’s oil, the one so carefully
saved for 100 years will be gone in less than 20 years. The saving considered – 100%, quite draconian a
choice – would affect no future generation. Even less it would any more realistic saving. Say the entire world
were able to engage into a 10% oil saving. Which is quite a lot, at least twice as much as required by the
Kyoto Protocol, which the world was unable to satisfy. Yet, the end of oil will come in 110 years rather than
in 100 years. Once again, no future generation will be affected whatsoever.
The point is this:kkkkkkkkkkikkkkk If not the finite or the infinite ones, what are, then, the resources worth to save? They are
those resources whose amount is infinite but whose availability is finite. Pretty much like my income: it is
infinite in the sense that to me, holding a tenure position, the income is guaranteed during my whole life; its
availability is finite because it is given to me quantized in monthly checks. Saving on oil is therefore
meaningless, not less than such extravagant a concept as sustainable development.
Well, you might say, perhaps the reason why we should save on oil is because oil costs money and, after all,
to save energy means to save money. I like this one: indeed, the only sensible reason to save energy is
because energy, in the form that is useful to us, doesn’t come upon us for free, and we save energy because
we need to save money. Germany has spent at least €80 billions in installing 17 GW of PV plants whose
electric production (12 billions kWh in 2010) has allowed them to save €840 millions in one year (the
electric kWh is quoted about €0.07 on the stock market). I’m not an economist, so you tell me whether
Germany has saved any money. Assuming no efficiency reduction, no maintenance costs and a (very long)
life of 30 years for the PV modules, Germany will have saved €25 billions in 30 years, having spent €80
billions today.
The only rationale for saving energy is to save money. Apparently, however, the green economy achieves
everything but saving money. Actually, it pretty well succeeds in wasting huge amounts of taxpayers’
money.
Some people mistakenly identify energy saving with not wasting it. Wasting energy means to burn fuel when
not needed, an occurrence too trivially contemptible to worth mentioning, and saving energy cannot be such
a trivial proposal, given that it seems to be at the center of the political agendas of the rulers of the world.
No, saving energy cannot mean to avoid using it when not needed, rather must mean to avoid using it when
needed. But this is exactly what makes us poorer. As said, whatever we do, is done by using energy, i.e.,
nowadays, by burning fossil fuels. To ask us to spare on energy use means to ask us to accept to be poorer
and lower our well–being. It means to lose jobs and to take back the path toward slavery. Saving energy is
the most dangerous maneuver we could ever make. To appreciate this statement, please look at Fig. 16,
where you can see how economic wealth is correlated with energy use.
100
1000
10000
100000
1 100 10000
Total Energy Consumption Per Capita (Kilogram Oil Equivalent)
GDP Per Capita ($)
- GDP: 2002
- Energy: 2001
Source: Globalis Indicator Data
UN Common Database
World Bank Database
CIA Database
North Korea
Congo
Nigeria
Yemen
Cuba
Sierra Leone
Iraq
Venezuela
China
Barundi
Rwanda
Mali
Russia
Saudi Arabia
Ukraine
Bahrain
Kuwait
Canada
USA
Pakistan
Norway
Guinea
Nepal
Costa Rica
Columbia
India
Syria
South
Korea
Japan
UK
Italy
Ireland
Spain
Iran
France
Kenya
Fig. 16 - Economic wealth is highly correlated with energy use
Some people mistakenly identify energy saving with energy efficiency. EU’s rulers do. It is not clear what
they mean. Our energy production and energy consumption devices are already quite efficient, very close to
their upper bound limit. An ideal thermal engine that works between a source 1000 K and a sink at 300 K,
has a 70% efficiency, but ideal engines do not exist. A less idealistic, yet theoretical, thermal engine that
works between those temperatures has a 55% efficiency, but theoretical engines do not exist either. Our
thermal engines are 45% efficient, pretty close to the theoretical limit: we can hardly go any further; we
cannot go against the laws of physics. We could still make a slight improvement, but nothing to get excited
about, nothing which to build an energy policy on. People interested into energy policy like to define the
energy efficiency of a country as the ratio between the gross domestic product and the primary energy
consumption, so that energy efficiency sounds as “getting more with less energy”. All this is fine, and I do
promote energy efficiency. However – and this is my point on the matter – I’m aware, and you, too, better be
aware, that as good as energy efficiency might be, it worsen our real problem, which is Hubbert’s curve,
displayed in Fig. 11. It is not hard to see why.
Whenever a good is available with an increased efficiency, the use of it increases, too. Since we have had a
very efficient system of sending and receiving letters – the email service – we all receive and send a larger
number of letters than we used to in the past. Since we have had a very efficient system to make phone calls
– the cell-phone technology – we all make and receive more phone calls than we used to in the past. Just the
same is with energy: once we have been able to manufacture very efficient refrigerators, we started putting a
deep-freezer next to them. And if cars were today still as efficient as those of 100 years ago, almost nobody
would have a car, and a lot of oil would have been saved. The bottom line is that a higher efficiency in
energy production or energy consumption is an excellent goal to pursue but, inevitably, will have the
consequence of increasing the energy demand. We can see from facts that this is so: during the last 15 years,
developed countries have improved their energy efficiency at a 1.3% per year rate, but in spite of that those
countries, during the same period, have increased their energy consumption at a 1.7% per year rate. Not in
spite of that, but because of that, we should better say. Please, be aware of this: energy efficiency will shift
Hubbert’s peak to the left, i.e., will make worse our real problem. Yet, I wish to stress it here, energy
efficiency is a lovely goal to pursue. For, by wisely increasing our energy consumption we increase our
well–being.
A quick comment on creating jobs is due. The urban myth is that those green-economy plants create jobs.
First of all, you should realize that it is not by producing energy but by consuming energy that jobs are
created. Otherwise it would be easy: just provide a bicycle to a million unemployed asking them to pedal,
thereby producing electric energy. It doesn’t work this way. Second, dreaming of creating jobs committing
ourselves into technologies that we have proved to be useless is like dreaming of creating jobs asking people
to dig graves during daytime and to fill them up again at night. It doesn’t work this way, either: those people
might have an income, but society would hardly get wealthier.
6. What to do?
I will answer the question limiting myself to the electric energy sector, and have chosen to do so for two
good reasons: 1) it is an important sector of our energy budget: about 40% today, but possibly and hopefully
growing in the future; 2) it is this sector where the EU’s energy policy is making the greatest disaster, by
promoting all those totally useless and tremendously expensive wind farms and photovoltaic roofs.
The answer to the question can be given by looking at Figs. 15, 17 and 18. Fig. 17 shows the capital
investment for a plant producing 1 GW electric, whereas Fig. 18 shows the relation among fuel’s prices.
PLANT’S COST TO PRODUCE 1 GW ELECTRIC
Natural Gas
1 G€
Coal
2 G€
Nuclear
3 G€
Wind
5 G€
Photovoltaic
50 G€
Fig. 17 – Plant’s cost to produce 1 GW electric
RELATION AMONG FUEL’S PRICES
Natural Gas > Coal > Uranium
Fig. 18 – Relation among fuel’s prices
The rules to follow for a wise energy policy then are:
1. Stop installing wind farms and PV roofs. As seen, they provide zero capacity to the electric system.
On top of that, their intermittency creates undesirable stability problems. Economically, they are of
no help because the conventional utilities must be there anyway, ready to go into operation whenever
the wind stops to blow or the sun stops to shine, a circumstance that requires us to pay anyway for
those utilities, even when they do not produce, if we want them to be there for us. From all the
above, we can conclude that wind farms and PV roofs should not be installed even if they were free.
However, this is not exactly what they are, as Fig. 17 shows.
2. Install as much hydropower plants as the local orography allows. Hydropower is the only meaningful
renewable-energy technology.
3. Install as many nuclear plants as necessary to cover the base load. Nuclear plants are the most
expensive conventional plants. However, they burn the cheapest fuel, whose availability is for
thousand years. Also, the technology requires them to work continuously, which is what the base
load requires, a circumstance that allows the quickest returns for the plant investments. For instance,
a 1.2-GW nuclear reactor costs about 3 G€ and produces about 1 GW electric. During its 60-years
life, it will have produced about 60 GW-year of electric energy, amounting to more than 500 TWh.
At a price of 7 c€/kWh, this means revenues in 60 years of about €40 billions against the initial
investment of €3 billions (it is worthwhile to mention at this point that less than 15% of the nuclear
kWh’s production costs are fuel’s costs). The base load is, for each country, about 70% of the
average consumption (Fig. 15). For instance, Italy’s electric consumption amounts to 40 GW, and
Italy’s base load is indeed 30 GW. Italy, then, should have about 30 GW nuclear, i.e., about 30
nuclear reactors. As for EU, its electric consumption amounts to about 380 GW: it should have not
less than 250 GW nuclear, whereas its electric production from nuclear is about 100 GW. Therefore,
the EU should plan to install about 150 nuclear reactors (30 of them, as said, should be in Italy). By
the way, by doing that the aimed 20%-CO2-emission reduction would be achieved.
4. Install coal plants to cover the regular load above the base load. Coal is an abundant resource, easy to
transport. Coal plants are not as expensive as nuclear ones and coal is cheaper than natural gas.
Nuclear and coal should provide, respectively, 50% and 30% of the electric-energy needs.
5. Devote natural gas only to supply the peak load. Gas plants (together with hydropower plants) are
easy to be put quickly into operation and because of this very well fit the electric demand at the
load’s peak. The relative low cost of the plants and the relative high cost of the fuel makes gas plants
best suitable to work, together with hydropower plants, as a “cold-reserve” for the exceptional peak
demand. Not only natural gas is a costly fuel, but it is also a precious resource, which would be
better to reserve for transportation uses. For a similar reason, oil should not be burned to produce
electricity: it is a costly and precious resource, of which the petrochemical industry knows how to
make a better use.
7. Conclusions
In conclusion, the ideal energy mix for electric production would be: 50% from nuclear, 30% from
coal, 15% from hydropower and 5% from gas. The 2010 EU’s electric-energy mix is shown in Fig. 15,
where the fossil-fuel contribution is 30% from coal and 20% from natural gas. A wise policy would be to
reduce natural gas in favor of nuclear. The real policy being pursued has been 1) to waste huge amount of
money into the useless green-economy plants, in the futile attempt of ruling the climate, and 2) to
irresponsibly slow down on nuclear, with the inevitable consequence of increasing the use of natural gas. By
pursuing such a policy EU’s leaders are digging our grave.
jueves, 27 de marzo de 2014
miércoles, 26 de marzo de 2014
I just made a new Voki. See it here:
I just made a new Voki. See it here:: http://www.voki.com/pickup.php?scid=9610362&height=267&width=200
jueves, 20 de marzo de 2014
visita del grupo local SEO Cantabria a Oyambre
http://seocantabria.blogspot.com.es/2014/01/salida-ornitologica-oyambre-26-de-enero.html
MARTES, 21 DE ENERO DE 2014
Resumen de la salida ornitológica al Parque Natural de Oyambre 26/01/14
El pasado domingo 26 de enero pudimos disfrutar de otra excelente jornada de campo, en esta ocasión estuvimos visitando el Parque Natural de Oyambre. Como ya es tradición en nuestras actividades, el buen tiempo acompañó la jornada.
Antes de comenzar el recorrido, Iñaki, uno de los integrantes de la salida, trajo un Arao común que había encontrado vivo (aunque algo aturdido) la tarde anterior en Merón; tras revisar su estado y viendo que parecía no tener problemas físicos, nos decidimos por liberarlo en la desembocadura de Oyambre; donde, después de unos minutos de incertidumbre, se decidió a nadar por la ría, incluso dando algún buceo en busca de presas.
Una vez liberado el ejemplar, empezamos a observar las primeras aves de la mañana... Gaviotas reidoras, Zarapitos reales, Archibebes claros, Cercetas comunes y los omnipresentes Martines pescadores, nos deleitaron con su presencia en varias partes del recorrido. Una de las sorpresas fue localizar 2 ejemplares de Ganso del Nilo; especie que visita de forma esporádica este espacio natural.
Tras recorrer las rías, y aprovechando que la presencia del sol incitaba al paseo, hicimos un pequeño recorrido por la campiña cercana. En ella descubrimos a uno de los Elanios comunes que suele cazar por esta zona; además de Mochuelo europeo, Alondras comunes, Halcón peregrino, Chovas piquirrojas y, la segunda sorpresa del día, un Alcaudón real que se encontraba posado sobre un cable; especie ésta, muy poco frecuente en la zona.
Para finalizar la mañana, nos acercamos a la ría de San Vicente de la Barquera; en su desembocadura, pudimos disfrutar del espectáculo que ofrecía el oleaje rompiendo contra la escollera, además de observar un Colimbo grande, un Cormorán moñudo y varios Alcatraces atlánticos que volaban hacia el Oeste. Por último, nos dirigimos al puente de la Maza, desde donde despedimos la jornada divisando las diferentes especies de limícolas que empezaban a moverse en busca de alimento, aprovechando el inicio de la bajada de la marea (Correlimos comunes, Chorlitejos grandes, Chorlitos grises, Zarapitos trinadores,...).
Y así terminó una salida más del Grupo Local, con el placer de haber compartido una jornada de campo con amigos y amantes de la naturaleza.
domingo, 16 de marzo de 2014
Warning Signs: How Pesticides Harm the Young Brain | The Nation
Warning Signs: How Pesticides Harm the Young Brain | The Nation
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
viernes, 7 de marzo de 2014
martes, 4 de marzo de 2014
The Great Global Warming Swindle Full Movie la estafa the swindle
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
sábado, 1 de marzo de 2014
martes, 25 de febrero de 2014
Exxon’s Pro-Fracking CEO Is Suing to Stop Fracking Near His Mansion | The Nation
Exxon’s Pro-Fracking CEO Is Suing to Stop Fracking Near His Mansion | The Nation
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
CRITICA FILOSOFICA PARA MANTENER LA VIDA SABER Y PODER PARA MANTENERNOS LIBRES COMOLA CAPACIDAD DE INDEPENDENCIA FUNDAMENTAL PARA LA VIDA
lunes, 24 de febrero de 2014
No queremos fracking, video con canción antifracking en Cantabria, España
We dont´t want the fracking in Spain, nor in Cantabria
sábado, 22 de febrero de 2014
Santa Clara study trip to West Cantabria WE FOUNDED A PUFFIN UN FRAILECILLO WOUNDED ON OYAMBRE BEACH
El día 13 de febrero de 2014 hicimos un viaje de estudio de campo para conocer más directamente los temas que estamos tratando de conocer acerca de medio ambiente y desarrollo sostenible
Este viaje forma parte de las actividades que venimos llevando a cabo dentro del Proyecto Comenius GREEN SKILLS FOR GLOBAL CHANGE
Había habido esos días una serie de temporales marítimos , y a causa de estos fuertes vientos y marejadas , apareció en la playa de Oytambre un frailecillo herido ( a wounded puffin ), no podía volar. Diego, del bachiller de artes del IES Santa Clara, de 1º A, lo adoptó con un admirable entusiasmo a lo largo de todo nuestro viaje, mimándolo al máximo. En inglés su nombre es el de puffin
Comenius field trip West Cantabria from Eliseo Rabadan Fernandez on Vimeo.
HAZ CLICK EN EL ENLACE PARA MAYOR INFORMACION, EN INGLES http://www.animalfactguide.com/animal-facts/atlantic-puffin/domingo, 16 de febrero de 2014
Visita a Occidente de Cantabria Proyecto Comenius IES Santa Clara
Visita al Occidente de Cantabria Proyecto Comenius Santa Clara on PhotoPeach
miércoles, 12 de febrero de 2014
Comenius Green Skills for Global Change. Students of Santa Clara made two field study visits in Santander City, Cantabria (Spain)
La Esperanza market and La Magdalena Park Ecological field study on PhotoPeach
These two field study activities are included in the Comenius Project, in which our School (IES Santa Clara. Santander City, Cantabria-Spain) is actually a partner, working together with other six european schools ( including Portugal, France, Turkey, Netherlands, Slovenia and Denmark). The Project´s name is GREEN SKILLS FOR GLOBAL CHANGE
1ºH bach. IES Santa Clara Visita al Parque de La Magdalena (Santander), proyecto Comenius Green Skills for Global Change
Estudiantes de 1ºH ( ciencias, IES Santa Clara) de bachiller realizaron una vista guiada al Parque de La Magdalena en Santander, la capital cántabra.
Fueron acompañados por el profesor Eliseo Rabadán, y forma parte del Proyecto Green Skills for Global Change, un Proyecto Comenius centrado en la temática del desarrollo sostenible a nivel local y las relaciones con el proceso de globalización
La visita fue guiada por especialistas del Ayuntamiento de la ciudad de Santander, que lleva a cabo un proyecto de educación ambiental y de recuperación de la flora y fauna autóctonas de Cantabria.
Esta y otras actividades que el Proyecto Comenius realiza, están directamente vinculadas con el Seminario de Sostenibilidad de nuestro Instituto, dirigido por el profesor Francisco Javier Alonso del Val, en el cual participan profesores de diversos departamentos
martes, 11 de febrero de 2014
Images taken during Comenius meeting in Portugal , 2014 January 15th-19th Spanish team and partners activities pics
Spanish Comenius team at Portugal Meeting on PhotoPeach
miércoles, 5 de febrero de 2014
domingo, 2 de febrero de 2014
sábado, 1 de febrero de 2014
viernes, 31 de enero de 2014
Back to the land in Romania
A pig, milk and cheap veg against EU agribusiness
Back to the land in Romania
The EU sends Europeanisation agents across Romania to end subsistence farming and encourage agricultural competition. But those who have turned to self-sufficient farming because of austerity resist the world of the CAP.
SOURCE http://mondediplo.com/2014/02/09romania
by Pierre Souchon
The ministry of agriculture car accelerated out of Bucharest and into the countryside, its speed camera detector at the ready. At the foot of the Carpathian mountains, discreet stakes indicated a field of the US seed company Pioneer’s genetically modified maize. The giant skeletons of abandoned steel factories lay amid hundreds of hectares of Agro Invest cereal crops, and immense hoardings advertised the Romanian agribusiness company’s appetite for “chernozem”, the black topsoil that is the most fertile land in Europe. “Look, it’s you!” said Gabriel Garban, director of communications at the Paying Agency for Rural Development and Fishery, as we passed a gleaming Michelin tyre factory. A little further on, a kestrel eyed an old peasant farmer sitting in long grass, his scythe by his side. He was reading a book, glancing up to keep an eye on his one cow. “He is cultivating his mind,” said Garban, reminding us of the words of the Romanian philosopher Lucian Blaga: “Eternity was born in the village.”
When we reached Sercaia in the centre of the country, eternity had put its foot on the accelerator. “The National Rural Development Programme (NRDP) is coming to your village,” announced a poster on the door of the town hall. In a tent at the football stadium six uniformed Europeanisation agents were giving a PowerPoint presentation on financing a dairy farm. Since 2007 Romania has been a beneficiary of the European Agriculture Fund for Rural Development (EAFRD), which is co-funding the initiative. The plan is to convert the 3.5 million Romanians who farm less than a hectare of land into entrepreneurs. The number of peasant farmers in Romania has reached a European record — 30% of the economically active population, compared with 28% in 1989. The collapse of Communism and the contraction of the industrial sector sent people back to the land. Property is often divided up among family members, and the average holding is two hectares, compared with 55 in France.
“The farmer we just passed typifies Romanian agriculture. He is uncompetitive,” said Garban. “How are you going to break into the European market with just five litres of milk?” His answer would be to attend the NRDP presentation, like the 30 Sercaia residents who had come along. “It’s very important to convince opinion leaders. The priest and the primary school teacher have both come,” said Garban’s colleague, Catalina Musat. The screen showed the financial operational targets that would allow a farmer to produce 24,000kg of tomatoes in five years in return for an investment of €23,754, of which €7,400 is a non-repayable government grant. Musat added: “Small farmers are not the potential beneficiaries though. We are aiming this more at people who want to start a business.”
‘I couldn’t care less’
People like agronomist Alexandru Strâmtu, 31, who showed us round his new organic blueberry farm. The EU provided half the funding — €300,000 — and he put up the other half. “I’m in debt but business is going well. I sell all the blueberries to a Portuguese company, which exports them to Germany, Chile. Sometimes I even see my fruit here.” But transporting them around the world is surely not very ecological? “Honestly, I couldn’t care less.”
Just outside Bârla, in the south, Hadi Khoury, 30, the Lebanese managing director of the Haditon group, welcomed us to his farm. He asked us to wear white overalls to prevent contamination of the 120,000 chickens kept in four buildings of the former collective farm (1). In association with 12 other businessmen, mostly from the Middle East, he produces a quarter of all the eggs eaten in Romania. “If you don’t have the stamp of the European Union, banks won’t even look at you. But if you do, they’ll come to you.” The EAFRD contributed €1m to the renovation.
“Romania’s fantastic,” he said. “These ex-Communist buildings cost me next to nothing, I pay my 25 employees very little, and the EU loans are substantial. The only problem is the Poles.” They are “unfair competition. They don’t have the same hygiene standards, and they get more subsidies than we do. That’s the problem with Europe — it’s great on modernisation and money, but we are all competing with each other.” The local MP and former secretary of state at the ministry of justice, Theodor Nicolescu, said: “Hadi’s success is an example to us all. Thanks to the European Union we are becoming competitive, and we are creating the conditions for the free market to operate and guide people’s behaviour.”
We spent the evening in a large room with a marble bathroom in a deserted tourist hotel set up with the support of the EAFRD. Garban and Musat said their parents had abandoned the family plot of land to work in the city, as physicists and fashion designers. Nonetheless, the gospodarie (house, courtyard, outbuildings and patch of land) remains a fundamental unit of social organisation. The ministry chauffeur, Ion Neagu, said he rented out his family’s three hectares to a farmer who was cultivating them in a partnership (2). “I’d rather beg in Paris than work the land,” he said, although he dreams of spending his retirement there.
The hotel’s cook disagreed: “I farm my gospodarie. I have pigs, chickens and cows. How else would I manage on my seasonal wages?” The young waitress said she was glad to get the benefit of her family’s plot, but wouldn’t dream of picking up a spade herself: “I don’t want to do my back in.” Attitudes are changing. As families lose interest in working the land, the culture of self-sufficiency is being abandoned.
A struggle to survive
Three hundred kilometres away at Vintu de Jos, far from the NRDP publicity tour, we met Teodor Vingarzan and his son Lucian. They are subsistence farmers, even though they have 50 hectares. Lucian, 34, an engineer, said he would rather work the family farm than earn, at best, €300 a month in town. His youngest son had to emigrate to the US to find work. Lucian invited us into the barn where he milked the oldest cow and handed us a bowl of warm milk. “There’s modernisation for you,” he said as he rinsed the bowl at the tap. “We only recently got running water.” The Vingarzans use the animal manure to fertilise their cereal crops, which they feed to their cattle. “At the end of the year we have a pig for Christmas, milk and eggs.”
It’s a struggle to survive, and Teodor blames the EU: “Our local produce is excellent, it is all organic, but we are being crushed by produce from western Europe. They are much more subsidised and mechanised, and so their food is cheaper than ours. I produce everything here but I can’t sell it. Go to the supermarket and you will see — the potatoes are German, Italian and French.” Vingarzan once believed in modernisation — immediately after Ceaușescu fell, he visited modern farms in Belgium, France and Austria. He was impressed, and decided to increase his family’s land (as land was being redistributed), buy equipment, and prosper. But “I was betrayed.”
When I met Achim Irimescu, secretary of state at the ministry of agriculture, in his office in Bucharest, I was surprised to hear him describe the merits of subsistence farming: “It plays a very important social role. This is a large number of people who are not unemployed, and who survive without asking the government for help.” This leading member of the Conservative Party does however want to “reintegrate them into the market and make them competitive through EU aid programmes for small farmers ... those who do not take action will disappear, because most are elderly peasants without anyone to pass their land onto. It’s the natural solution.” But when he described government measures — increasing the minimum size of farm that can apply for funding, making investment conditional on the accumulation of land — and pointed out that these laws have already reduced the numbers claiming direct payments by 300,000, the process did not seem quite so natural.
Competition is the solution advocated in Romania, as it was in France in the 1960s, by agricultural scientists and managers. Cristina Pocol, who teaches rural economy at the University of Agricultural Sciences and Veterinary Medicine of Cluj-Napoca, listed what she describes as Romania’s handicaps, such as small parcels of land, low productivity and low mechanisation. She pointed to an apple orchard seen on television: “The operation is enormous, everything is computerised, the product is competitive. That’s the road we should take.”
Our produce is too dear
Convinced by travels to China and Germany, Tiberiu Biris tried to go down that road. He set up an apiary cooperative in Blaj, bringing together 200 producers and the latest technology. They package around 400 tons of honey a year, most of which is exported. “Romanians can’t buy Romanian honey,” Teodor Parau, who owns 200 hives, said with regret. “Our product is too expensive. It is bought by big western importers.” The middlemen keep the prices so low that Biris fears he may have to close down the cooperative. The honey is competitive though — around half the price of honey from western Europe.
One of the paradoxes of agrarian liberalism in Romania is that farmers are gaining market share abroad but cannot feed their own people: 70% of food is imported. Driven by the EU, distorted competition has favoured the rise of agriculture for export. In 10 years, almost 1m hectares, or 6.5% of usable agricultural land (3), has passed into the hands of foreign investors. EU subsidies, low property prices and cheap labour are concentrating the business into the hands of a few. In 2013 the government introduced a bill freeing up the sale of land. A year ago the agriculture minister, Daniel Constantin, had to explain why he owed one of the biggest industrial farm owners in the country several hundred thousand euros (4). Two of Constantin’s predecessors, Valeriu Tabără and Stelian Fuia, worked for the multinational Monsanto.
Conflicts of interest are obvious and the political policy clear: in return for agreements signed with the International Monetary Fund in 2009 and 2011, the Romanian government cut 200,000 public sector jobs, reduced public sector salaries by a quarter and raised VAT to 24%. Pay is low and social protection weak, driving Romanians to emigrate. In 2007 around 12% of Romanians worked abroad, mostly in low-skilled jobs.
As if nothing has been learnt, the EU’s Common Agricultural Policy (CAP) has brought Romania the same policies adopted by western Europe in the 1960s. But at that time the issue of self-sufficiency had been settled, and the labour market was able to absorb unskilled workers from the countryside, who often did well in the city and moved up the social ladder. The contract the NRDP is proposing today in Romania — that peasants should apply to large institutions for funding — reinforces the established inequalities between small-scale and large-scale farms, and between subsistence farmers and industrial entrepreneurs better placed to get European funds.
This is not the first time rural Romania has seen prophets of “good practice” — from 1948 onwards the Communist Party’s propaganda department organised cinema tours of the countryside showing Soviet and domestic films extolling collectivisation.
Grow your own
“It makes me so sad to kill them,” said Cezara Fiţ, who teaches the history of music at Alba Iulia secondary school, as she contemplated 30 freshly killed chickens in her garden. Her husband, Iosif Fiţ, a member of the national union of composers, spread their home produce on the table: tomatoes, cucumbers, red wine and plum brandy. “The excellent local vegetables sold by the old ladies at the market are too expensive for us,” said Cezara. “The vegetables in the big supermarkets are affordable, but they have come from far away and are full of chemicals.”
The couple have been converted to the benefits of farming, which also helps one of their daughters, a teacher whose €180 a month earnings are not enough to pay her bills. Austerity measures imposed by international institutions encourage people to turn to self-sufficiency — in Greece, after the IMF’s rescue packages, tens of thousands of city dwellers returned to the land. Composers and teachers work the fields. “Ceaușescu could never have dreamed of this,” said Iosif.
Disgusted by what he sees as a corrupt political class, he thinks only a Malthusian disaster will sort things out. “A big global catastrophe would kill two or three billion people. The survivors would rebuild the world on more moral principles.” Vingarzan would like to see the return of royalty. Ramona Dominicioiu and Attila Szocs, activists with Eco Ruralis, the only Romanian organisation to defend small peasant farmers, try to raise funds to save tomato seeds and reject all politicians as corrupt.
Corruption, condemned by everyone, including President Traian Băsescu, who has made it one of his main concerns, makes it hard to see how the public authorities can find a solution; it also masks policies put in place for personal enrichment. The European Commission scolds Romania for how it uses EU funds, but does not question the course it is taking: “Membership of the European Union ... has been accompanied by extensive reforms which have contributed to the modernisation of the country, and Romanian citizens have been able to benefit from this,” said the Commission’s president José Manuel Barroso (5). The IMF believes the agreements it signed with Romania have been “crowned with success” (6).
Such brilliant political success was no doubt behind the appointment of Romania’s former agriculture minister Dacian Cioloș to the post of European Commissioner for Agriculture and Rural Development in 2009, where he has just renegotiated reform of the CAP. Romanian peasants do not see this as a reason to be proud.
miércoles, 29 de enero de 2014
domingo, 26 de enero de 2014
miércoles, 8 de enero de 2014
martes, 7 de enero de 2014
Climate Change, Global Warming and the Big Freeze
Climate Change, Global Warming and the Big Freeze
Sobre el cambio climático, conisderado como una nematología . Definición de nematología: Las nematologías son aquellas doctrinas que se caracterizan por organizar las nebulosas ideológicas, entendidas éstas como contenidos ideológicos muy poco sistematizados. Son especulaciones de carácter ideológico que se organizan alrededor de instituciones religiosas, políticas, militares, etc. Por ejemplo, la teología positiva es una nematología de las religiones terciarias
Fuente de la def. http://symploke.trujaman.org/index.php?title=Nematolog%EDa
Sobre el cambio climático, conisderado como una nematología . Definición de nematología: Las nematologías son aquellas doctrinas que se caracterizan por organizar las nebulosas ideológicas, entendidas éstas como contenidos ideológicos muy poco sistematizados. Son especulaciones de carácter ideológico que se organizan alrededor de instituciones religiosas, políticas, militares, etc. Por ejemplo, la teología positiva es una nematología de las religiones terciarias
Fuente de la def. http://symploke.trujaman.org/index.php?title=Nematolog%EDa
jueves, 2 de enero de 2014
Suscribirse a:
Entradas (Atom)